Blog2017-06-03T09:45:07-07:00

Senate floor #006: The Mikulski amendment

Senator Mikulski’s amendment is a benefit mandate. Here is some key text from the amendment:

“… coverage shall, at a minimum provide coverage for and shall not impose any cost sharing requirements for …

(4) with respect to women, such additional preventive care and screenings not described in paragraph (1) as provided for in comprehensive guidelines supported by the Health Resources and Services Administration for purposes of this paragraph.”

This is a Congressionally-mandated benefit as determined by an Executive Branch bureaucracy. As Senator Mikulski said when introducing the amendment:

The essential aspect of my amendment is that it guarantees women access to lifesaving preventive services and screenings. … It does it by getting rid of, or minimizing, high copays and high deductibles that are often overwhelming hurdles for women to access screening programs.

Of course no elected official wants to vote against an amendment that appears to help women get access to preventive services and screenings.

Is it the government’s job to determine this? Do you want your health insurance benefits and copayments to be determined by a combination of officials from the federal Health Resources and Services Administration, and Members of Congress? Or would you prefer to have a range of options when you buy insurance? Should health insurance benefits one-size-fits all?

Does your view change when the chiropractors muster the political power to get their benefits mandated? I saw it happen in the 90’s.

Remember also that each mandated benefit, especially with low or no cost-sharing, raises insurance premiums for everyone.

Tuesday, 1 December 2009|

Senate floor #005: The kiddie table

Here’s a funny quote from Senate Republican Whip Jon Kyl yesterday on whether the process so far has been bipartisan:

The majority leader said that Republicans have had a seat at the table. I am on one of the two major committees, the Finance Committee. I think one amendment was adopted. It was an amendment offered by a Republican and a Democrat on the committee. There were well over 100 amendments that Republicans offered that were all shot down, defeated, largely on party line votes. I say to my distinguished friend from Nevada that maybe we have a seat at the table but it is a little like the kids table at Thanksgiving dinner where you are told to mind your manners and keep the noise down. That is the way Republicans feel about our role at the table in fashioning this legislation.

More importantly, Sen. Kyl responded to Leader Reid’s comments about something v. nothing:

I do, with all deference, disagree with his comment that the motivation of Republicans is to do nothing. Of course, he frequently says doing nothing is not an option. Nobody is arguing about doing nothing. Republicans have presented some very good ideas to do something, to do a lot of somethings. Our ideas have been rejected. Let’s don’t get into false debate about doing something or nothing and the only alternative is the bill that is on the Senate floor. There are alternatives, and I will discuss one group of alternatives we have presented in a moment.

Tuesday, 1 December 2009|

Senate floor #004: The Senate’s unfinished to do list

Senate Republican Leader McConnell pointed out yesterday that the Senate has a lot of unfinished and important business to complete before the end of the year:

In addition to that, there are a number of things that actually must be done this month: We have a debt ceiling expiring, or needing to be expanded, according to the Administration; we have not passed appropriations bills; there are tax extenders that expire at the end of the year; there are PATRIOT Act provisions that expire at the end of the year.

Some of these items can be passed quickly, if there is bipartisan consensus on the substance. If, however, the majority wants to make changes to these laws, then Leader Reid will need to devote floor time to debating and possibly amending or having cloture votes on these bills.

Tuesday, 1 December 2009|

Senate floor #003: Transparently??

Here is Leader Reid on the Senate floor yesterday:

We will do this work transparently, and we will do this work tirelessly. That may mean debating and voting late at night.

A bit later, Leader Reid returned to this argument:

The process for developing this legislation has been very transparent. In fact, the hearings held in the Finance Committee were done very publicly, and that is an understatement. For weeks and weeks, members of that committee couldn’t walk out of the room without being questioned by the press. The press was present at most of their meetings. So both the HELP and Finance Committees marked up their legislation in public markups. Republican and Democratic members of both committees offered numerous amendments, all of which were available to the public. Republican and Democratic members voted for or against those amendments in a public and transparent way, and each committee member can be held fully accountable to their constituents for all of those votes.

The merged bill before us is entirely consistent with the provisions produced in those public markups. The bill has been fully available on the Internet for about 2 weeks. So each and every American has had the opportunity, if they wanted, to read the text of the legislation and to communicate their views with their Senators.

 

Leader Reid appears to be defining transparency as an open committee process, floor debate, and amendment process. He wrote his substitute amendment, however, behind closed doors with senior Administration officials in a process that was anything but transparent.

Tuesday, 1 December 2009|

Senate floor #002: Nothing is better than something bad

Here is more from Leader Reid yesterday on the Senate floor:

While we disagree at times, let us at least agree that doing nothing is not an option. While each of us may not say yes to each word of this bill as it currently reads, let us at least agree that simply saying no isn’t enough.

I disagree with this because I have the following ranking:

  1. Good bill
  2. Current law (e.g., nothing new enacted)
  3. Bad bill

I think Leader Reid’s bill falls into category three, so I believe blocking it would be better than enacting it. My preferred good bill probably won’t happen this year. I would hope, however, that if this bill were blocked, that Democrats would then reach out to Republicans and begin to enact incremental reforms that might push in what I believe to be the right policy direction.

You may differ with me on whether the Reid bill is better or worse than nothing. My point here is simply to debunk the “simply saying no isn’t enough” argument. Sometimes, nothing is better than something (bad).

Tuesday, 1 December 2009|

Senate floor #001: Leader Reid’s bankruptcy argument

Here is a quote from Leader Reid’s opening statement on the Senate floor yesterday:

Leader Reid: Is that a crisis in America? 750,000 people filing for bankruptcy and about 70 percent of them filing because of health care costs, with 62 percent of those who filed for bankruptcy because of health care costs having health insurance?

I have not checked the Leader’s numbers. I have been told they are overstated, but let’s take them as facts. That would mean that 525,000 people file for bankruptcy because of health care costs.

Let’s make a wildly overoptimistic assumption that this bill would prevent half of them from entering bankruptcy. That’s about 263,000 people.

Compare that to the 16 million people whom CBO says (in 2016) would remain uninsured and yet have to pay a penalty tax because they didn’t comply with the individual mandate.

For each person who would avoid bankruptcy as a result of this bill, more than 60 would remain uninsured and have to pay a penalty tax of almost $800 per year.

Is that worth it?

Tuesday, 1 December 2009|

A penalty tax inequity in the Reid bill

Under Leader Reid’s amendment, in the year 2019 about 16 million U.S. citizens would be uninsured and be forced to pay a penalty tax of almost $800 per year. About eight million illegal aliens would be uninsured and would owe no penalty tax. Both groups would get their health care through a combination of out-of-pocket spending and use of uncompensated care in emergency rooms and free health clinics.

This seems unfair.

Details follow for those who care. Warning: the details get weedy quickly. You might want to skip them. I am including them mostly for experts and reporters who may want to follow up on this. If you are a policy amateur but have been reading this blog for more than a week or two, feel free to dive in. You can handle the complexity.

If you want to know my guess about why the Reid amendment has this problem, please skip to the last section of this post.


Background

Both the House and Senate bills require applicable individuals to buy health insurance. If you are an applicable individual and you do not have insurance, you pay a penalty tax to the IRS. The taxes are different:

  • House bill: roughly 2.5% of adjusted gross income;
  • Senate bill: $750 per person in 2016, with smaller phase-in amounts in 2014 and 2015.

Each bill defines exceptions to the term applicable individual. I will focus on the exceptions related to citizenship and presence in the United States.

Thanks to help from some smart friends, here is how I read the language:

Do the individual mandate and penalty tax apply?

Uninsured U.S. citizen

Uninsured and not a citizen

Living in the U.S.

Living outside the U.S.

Legally in the U.S.

Illegally in the U.S.

Resident in the U.S.

Not resident in the U.S.

Resident in the U.S.

Not resident in the U.S.

House-passed

Yes

No

Yes

No

Yes

No

Reid amendment

Yes

Yes

Yes

??

No

??

This table is more complex than I would like, in part because of the different approaches in the two bills.

The key is the comparison of the two red cells. Under the Reid amendment, beginning in 2011:

  • If you are a U.S. citizen living in the U.S. and you are uninsured, you pay the penalty tax.
  • If you are illegally in the U.S. and you are uninsured, you do not pay the penalty tax.

In 2016 the Reid amendment’s penalty tax (with some exceptions) is $750 per person. It phases up from $95 in 2014 and $350 in 2015. By 2019, the penalty tax would be $794 per person (using CBO’s inflation assumptions.)

CBO says that, in 2019 under the Reid amendment there would be about 24 million uninsured people, “about one-third of whom would be unauthorized immigrants” (p. 8). So there would be about 16 M people in the Yes boxes, and about 8 M in the No box.


Legislative language

The key language is in section 5000(A)(d)(3), as would be added by section 1501(b) of the Reid amendment: “…

[applicable person] shall not include an individual … if the individual is not … an alien lawfully present in the United States.” The double (triple?) negative makes the full sentence somewhat more confusing. You can find it below.

To quote one of my smart friends, The words “not lawfully present in the United States” are the magic phrase that legislative counsel uses to identify those we colloquially refer to as illegal immigrants.

Here’s the language in the Reid amendment, beginning on page 324:

Se. 1501(b) —

SEC. 5000A. REQUIREMENT TO MAINTAIN MINIMUM ESSENTIAL COVERAGE.

    • (a) REQUIREMENT TO MAINTAIN MINIMUM ESSENTIAL COVERAGE. An applicable individual shall for each month beginning after 2013 ensure that the individual, and any dependent of the individual who is an applicable individual, is covered under minimum essential coverage for such month.
    • (b) SHARED RESPONSIBILITY PAYMENT.
      • (1) IN GENERAL. If an applicable individual fails to meet the requirement of subsection (a) for 1 or more months during any calendar year beginning after 2013, then, except as provided in subsection (d), there is hereby imposed a penalty with respect to the individual in the amount determined under subsection (c).
    • [ skip to page 329 ]
    • (d) APPLICABLE INDIVIDUAL. For purposes of this section —
      • (1) IN GENERAL. The term “applicable individual” means, with respect to any month, an individual other than an individual described in paragraph (2), (3), or (4).
      • (2) RELIGIOUS EXEMPTIONS. …
      • (3) INDIVIDUALS NOT LAWFULLY PRESENT. Such term shall not include an individual for any month if for the month the individual is not a citizen or national of the United States or an alien lawfully present in the United States.
      • (4) INCARCERATED INDIVIDUALS. Such term shall not include an individual for any month if for the month the individual is incarcerated, other than incarceration pending the disposition of charges.

(d)(3) would benefit greatly from some parentheses. It’s easiest to understand if you just look at its title: individuals not lawfully present are an exception to applicable individual in (1). Colloquially, this means that illegal aliens are not applicable individuals subject to the shared responsibility payment in (b)(1).


Why did they do this?

I also would not be at all surprised if most Senators do not yet understand this consequence. Complex policy changes often end up with a few of these cul-de-sacs, and they can cause the proponents serious heartburn. The staff who drafted the bill certainly do understand this.

Assuming this isn’t just an oversight, the bill drafters were forced into a no-win choice. Here is my guess.

They decided to include an individual mandate. To make the mandate effective, they had to include a penalty tax for noncompliance.

The problem is that some people will ignore the mandate and pay the penalty tax. CBO says that some of these people are rational: the cost of insurance is greater than the penalty tax, so they choose to remain uninsured.

CBO says others are irrational. For them, the calculation suggests they “should” be better off by purchasing insurance, but for whatever reason they choose not to.

The penalty tax can be thought of in three different ways:

  1. It’s an incentive to get people to comply with the mandate. The bill drafters almost certainly don’t want people to end up uninsured and paying a penalty tax. They want the incentive to encourage everyone to buy health insurance.
  2. It’s a penalty for those who ignore the mandate. This is closely related to the incentive, but a slightly different concept.
  3. It’s a free-rider fee for those who go uninsured and free ride on emergency rooms and free clinics.

Now, what should they do about illegal aliens? Assuming they need an individual mandate, they have four policy options, which I’ll label A, B, C, and D:

How should illegal aliens be treated?

Mandate & penalty tax apply?

Yes

No

Eligible for insurance & subsidies?

Yes

A

B

No

C

D

Each option has serious downsides.

Option A: Illegal aliens are treated like U.S. citizens. They can buy insurance through exchanges, receive subsidies, and are subject to the mandate and penalty tax.

  • Problem: Most Members of Congress don’t want to subsidize illegal aliens.

Option B: Illegal aliens can buy insurance through exchanges, receive subsidies, but are not subject to the mandate and penalty tax.

  • This is even less acceptable to those Members who reject option A. Illegal aliens would be treated better than U.S. citizens.

Option C: Illegal aliens cannot buy insurance through exchanges or receive subsidies. The mandate and penalty tax apply to them if they do not have insurance.

  • If you think of the penalty tax as an incentive or a penalty for those who choose to go without insurance, then this option doesn’t work, because you’re not giving illegal aliens an option to comply with the mandate.
  • If, however, you think of the penalty tax as a free-rider fee, in which those without insurance are, in effect, paying the government to cover the costs they impose on the uncompensated care system, then this option is OK.

Option D: Illegal aliens cannot buy insurance through exchanges or receive subsidies. The mandate and penalty tax do not apply to them.

  • This is what the Reid amendment does.
  • If you think of the penalty tax as an incentive or a penalty, then this option makes sense. Since they cannot buy insurance, it’s “fair,” some would argue, not to penalize them for a choice they don’t have.
  • If, however, you think of the penalty tax as a free-rider fee, then the inequity with U.S. citizens who remain uninsured causes an apparent fairness problem. I highlight this inequity in the title and opening paragraph of this post.

I am not too surprised that a bill drafted to keep the Left happy would choose option D. I don’t know how well it will sit with the swing votes Leader Reid needs to hold 60.

For the record, I would choose option E: no individual mandate. The above problem goes away, but with even bigger consequences for the legislation. Leader Reid needs the mandate to make his bill work, so he is stuck with the other four bad options.

Are the moderate/nervous Democratic Senators comfortable voting for (or to begin debate on) a bill that appears to treat uninsured American citizens more harshly than it treats uninsured illegal aliens?

We shall see.

Saturday, 21 November 2009|

Breaking the no middle class tax increase pledge (again)

On September 12, 2008 in Dover, New Hampshire, then-candidate Obama said:

I can make a firm pledge. Under my plan, no family making less than $250,000 a year will see any form of tax increase. Not your income tax, not your payroll tax, not your capital gains taxes, not any of your taxes.

<

p align=”center”>

[youtube=http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Q8erePM8V5U&w=425&h=344]

On February 4, 2009, President Obama signed Public Law #111-3, the Children’s Health Insurance Program Reauthorization Act of 2009. Section 701 of this law increased tobacco taxes, effective April 1, 2009. Since most smokers have annual family income less than $250,000, this was a clear violation of the President’s pledge.

If anyone argues the President was only talking about “Under my plan,” and that his “firm pledge” does not apply to legislation enacted by Congress, Calvin Woodward of the Associated Press wrote of the Dover campaign speech:

He repeatedly vowed “you will not see any of your taxes increase one single dime.”

Let’s look at the Reid health care bill in the same context. If the President were to sign the Reid bill in its current form, would he violate the Dover pledge?

  1. The clearest violation is the 5% excise tax on cosmetic surgery and similar procedures (including teeth whitening). I assume that cosmetic surgery and similar procedures are skewed toward the high end of the income distribution, but there certainly are many people getting these treatments with annual family income less than $250,000.
  2. The bill would allow State insurance exchanges “to charge assessments or user fees to participating health insurers, or to otherwise generate funding, to support its operations.” [ §1311(d)(5)(A) ] Health insurers would pass these “assessments or user fees” through to consumers as higher premiums. This would affect anyone who buys health insurance, including those with family income less than $250,000.
  3. The bill would impose a 40% excise tax on health coverage in excess of $8,500 (individuals) / $23,000 (families). While policies this generous are almost certainly skewed higher on the income distribution, there are definitely families with income less than $250,000 receiving these plans. Again, health insurers would pass these tax increases through to those families.
  4. The bill would increase taxes on all health insurance plans, as well as on brand-name drugs and biologics, and on medical devices. These tax increases would affect anyone who buys these goods, even if their family income is less than $250,000.
  5. According to CBO, “By 2019, … the number of nonelderly people who are uninsured would be reduced by about 31 million, leaving about 24 million nonelderly residents uninsured (about one-third of whom would be unauthorized immigrants.)” (p. 8 ) These roughly 16 million people would pay “penalties” of $95 per adult in 2014, $350 per adult in 2015, and $750 per adult in 2016 and later. You’re charged half as much for each kid. Most of these 16 million people paying higher taxes will have family income less than $250,000 and will pay higher “penalties,” although not all will pay these full amounts.
  6. The bill would create a new 0.5 percentage point increase in payroll taxes on individuals with incomes greater than $200,000 in 2013 and families with incomes greater than $250,000 in 2013. Since these amounts are for 2013 and not indexed, someone making $233K in 2009 would be affected by this in 2013, assuming 1% annual real wage growth and CBO’s assumptions about inflation. If you’re making $220K this year, you’ll probably be hit by the new tax in 2016. $210K this year, you first get bit in 2017, and so on.

These are six tax increases (eight if you split #4 into its three components) that would violate the President’s pledge. I believe #1, #5, and #6 are indisputable.

The Administration could argue that #2, #3, and #4 don’t violate the letter of the President’s pledge, in that the incidence of the tax falls on the seller of the good, rather than on the purchaser of the good. But almost every economist will say that the economic impact of those tax increases would be felt by the person who buys that good, meaning these provisions at a minimum violate the spirit of the President’s pledge.

I would also argue that someone who would not otherwise buy health insurance, but does so to avoid the individual mandate / penalty, is being taxed. But I didn’t want the philosophical debate that underlies my view to detract from the conclusion derived from the above list.

Will President Obama sign such a bill that repeatedly breaks his “firm pledge”?

When the Administration issues its Statement of Administration Policy on the Reid bill, will it raise these objections?

Friday, 20 November 2009|

The 72-hour rule

Six weeks ago eight Senate Democrats sent Leader Reid a letter with a “plan for greater transparency.” Sen. Blanche Lincoln (D-AR) also issued a press release:

Citing the right of Arkansans to know in advance what health care changes that Senators will be voting on later this month, U.S. Senator Blanche Lincoln (D-Ark) today led a group of Democratic Senators in pressuring Senate leaders for greater transparency in the health insurance reform debate.

Here is the sentence relevant to the upcoming cloture vote:

The legislative text and complete budget scores from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) of the health care legislation considered on the Senate floor should be made available on a website the public can access for at least 72 hours prior to the first vote to proceed to the legislation.

The bill text was posted Wednesday evening.  The CBO score was available late last night (I first saw an emailed copy just after 11 PM EST.)

Following the Lincoln 72-hour rule, that means the cloture vote on the motion to proceed should not occur until late Saturday night.

It will be interesting to see how those eight Senators prioritize sticking to the letter of their plan, versus inconveniencing their colleagues and making them stay late Saturday night.

The eight Senators are:

  1. Sen. Blanche Lincoln (D-AR)
  2. Sen. Evan Bayh (D-IN)
  3. Sen. Mary Landrieu (D-LA)
  4. Sen. Joe Lieberman (D-CT)
  5. Sen. Claire McCaskill (D-MO)
  6. Sen. Ben Nelson (D-NE)
  7. Sen. Mark Pryor (D-AR)
  8. Sen. Jim Webb (D-VA)
Thursday, 19 November 2009|

Major tax increases in the Reid health care bill

The following is from the Joint Tax Committee estimate of the revenue effects of the Reid bill. I have listed provisions with major revenue effects (+$20 B / 10 years) and a few others that have significant policy or political impacts. There are some smaller changes as well, which you can see for yourself in the 3-page document. All revenue figures are revenues raised over the ten-year period 2010-2019.

  1. 40% excise tax on health coverage in excess of $8,500 (individuals) / $23,000 (families). Amounts are indexed for inflation by CPI-U + 1% … begins in 2013 … $149 B tax increase
  2. Additional 0.5% Medicare (Hospital Insurance) tax on wages in excess of $200,000 ($250,000 for joint filers) … begins in 2013 – $54 B tax increase
  3. Impose annual fee on manufacturers and importers of branded drugs … begins in 2009 … $22 B tax increase
  4. Impose annual fee on manufacturers and importers of certain medical devices … begins in 2009 … $19 B tax increase
  5. Impose annual fee on manufacturers and importers of health insurance plans … begins in 2009 … $60 B tax increase
  6. Cut in half (to $500K) the amount of an executive’s compensation that a health plan can deduct from its corporate income taxes … begins in 2013 – $600 million tax increase
  7. Impose 5% excise tax on cosmetic surgery and similar procedures … begins for surgery in 2010 … $6 B tax increase!

In total the bill would raise taxes by $370 B over ten years.

Here’s some reaction to these provisions. Updates since Wednesday night are in green.


Excise tax on high-cost plans (section 9001, beginning on page 1979)

It appears Leader Reid did, as rumored, raise slightly the limits in the Kerry excise tax on high cost plans, exempting some slightly more expensive health plans from taxation. It appears he substituted (2), the new Medicare payroll tax increase to cover the lost revenue.

The amounts in (1), relative to the Finance Committee, look like the result of an aggregate constraint from the unions. The Baucus / Finance Committee bill had limits of $8K / $21K and raised $201 B. The Reid limits of $8.5K / $21K are only slightly different, but raise $149 B. It looks like someone said “Get the Kerry tax number down from $200 B to under $150 B.”

From my perspective, this is crazy. Reid and Senate Democrats now have to defend themselves on two major tax increase policies rather than one. If you’re going to take the political hit for the Kerry tax on high cost plans, you might as well squeeze as much revenue as possible out of it. I assume he did this because someone forced him by threatening to oppose the bill (unions? one or more Senators?).

Medicare payroll tax increase (section 9015, beginning on page 2040)

Wow. It’s incredible that a Democratic leader would propose this.

Current law:

  • Wages up to $106,800 in 2009 (and in 2010) are subject to payroll taxes of 15.3%: 12.4% Social Security + 2.9% Medicare.
  • Wages above $106,800 are subject to payroll taxes of 2.9%.

My reading of section 9014 of the bill tells me that Leader Reid proposes the following addition (changes in red):

  • For individuals, wages between $106,800 and $200,000 for individuals are subject to payroll taxes of 2.9%.
  • For individuals, wages above $200,000 are subject to payroll taxes of 3.4%. That’s a 0.5 percentage point tax increase. So for each $1K you make above $200K, you would pay $5 more in payroll taxes.
  • For joint filers, wages between $106,800 and $250,000 for individuals are subject to payroll taxes of 2.9%.
  • For individuals, wages above $250,000 are subject to payroll taxes of 3.4%. That’s a 0.5 percentage point tax increase. So for each $1K you make above $250K, you would pay $5 more in payroll taxes.
  • These threshold amounts of $200K and $250K are not indexed for inflation or wages, so more real income in each subsequent year will be subject to the 0.5 percentage point tax increase.
  • The additional 0.5 percentage point tax increase comes on the employee side, so you still pay income taxes on these additional amounts of taxes paid.

With this proposal, Senator Reid is leading Democrats across a major philosophical threshold. Since Social Security was created in the 30’s and Medicare in 1965, payroll tax revenues have been “dedicated” to financing these programs. While not all funding to finance Medicare comes from payroll taxes, all funding from the Medicare payroll tax finances Medicare. In other words, the 2.9% Hospital Insurance payroll tax that you and your employer pay on your wages is all supposed to offset Medicare spending. That is part of the social insurance model, in which everyone pays in a fraction of their wages, and everyone receives benefits later.

I am not a fan of the social insurance model, because it is non-transparent: most people think their individual taxes paid are being used to finance their benefits, when in fact the funds are used to subsidize other people’s benefits. But the social insurance model and dedicated payroll taxes have been a core principle of Social Security and Medicare financing since they were created, and advocates (especially on the Left) of those programs have fiercely defended this principle.

Leader Reid’s bill would use new Medicare payroll taxes to finance a new health entitlement outside of Medicare. His bill would turn Medicare payroll taxes into a general financing mechanism like the income tax. There is a slippery-slope argument against this that I would normally expect from the Left. If Republicans (or my former boss) had proposed this, I would expect AARP to come unglued and raise fears among seniors that, if this proposal becomes law, future Congresses might take payroll tax revenues and use them for highways or defense or other non-social insurance spending. I am interested to see how AARP reacts. Will they support the Reid bill as they did the House bill? (Reporters: There’s a story for you. Ask AARP.)

In addition, Social Security and Medicare payroll taxes have always worked from the bottom of the wage scale upward, because they are traditionally tied to benefit eligibility. Leader Reid is now creating a “donut hole” in which there are three rate “brackets.” This initiates and lays the groundwork for the future expansion of a progressive tax rate structure for payroll taxes. This makes it easier for future lawmakers to raise payroll taxes to finance other parts of government, because they’re just “taxing the rich.” While the Reid proposal applies only to wages at the top of the distribution, the principle would be in place to justify raising payroll taxes in that $106K – $200K in the future. Watch out.

Both of these are enormous precedents, long-term structural game changers in how we finance our government.

The non-indexing for inflation raises an interesting question about whether it breaks President Obama’s pledge. Was his $250K limit in real or nominal dollars?

This provision is a big risk for moderate Senate Democrats.

Tax experts – it looks like they’re doing something tricky by using “taxpayer” rather than “individual” as in section 3101(b) of the I.R.C. I invite further explanation if this is significant.

Taxes on branded drugs, medical devices, and health plans (section 9008 on page 2010, section 9009 on page 2020, and section 9010 on page 2026)

The drug tax is a tax on “Big Pharma.” Bigger drug companies would pay higher taxes. For instance, a branded drug company with sales of $5M – $125M would pay taxes on only 10% of its gross sales, while one with >$400 M of sales would pay taxes based on 100% of its gross sales. (See p. 2012 of the bill.)

It is also applied only to brand name drugs, not generics. I would like to hear the policy rationale for this. The political rationale is simple: shaft the big brand-name Pharma companies. With exceptions, brand-name drug companies generally lean R, generic drug companies generally lean D.

In each case, I expect the providers will pass most of the tax increase on to consumers in the form of higher prices.

There are also a bunch of reporting requirements that at first glance look as if they are laying the intellectual groundwork for the future imposition of price controls. I invite further explanation from someone with expertise in drug pricing and rebates.

I know of no legitimate policy rationale for any of these taxes. They are derived from the following logic:

  • If the government spends more on health insurance, these two industries would make more money.
  • The government needs tax revenues.
  • So we’ll tax these industries to capture some of their increased revenues.

Shafting the health plan executives (section 9014 on page 2035)

I’m torn between hating the policy and chuckling at the political naivete of leaders of the health insurance industry. Unlike the taxes on big Pharma and medical device firms, here Leader Reid is going after the health plan executives’ individual compensation. He’s making it more expensive for a health plan to pay its executives more than $500K. Note that the higher taxes would apply to income earned paid in 2013 or later, even if that income was earned as early as 2010.

It’s terrible policy to single out the compensation of any particular industry. Wall Street: if this becomes law, you’re next in the crosshairs.

This is gratuitous political punishment of an unpopular constituency. The section is titled “Limitation on excessive remuneration paid by certain health insurance providers.” It raises $600 M over 10 years, and is thus insignificant as a pay-for.

How’s that political alliance working out for you guys?

Rather than trying to repeal this section, I’ll bet some creative Republican Senator offers an amendment to extend it to trial attorneys involved in medical malpractice cases.

Cosmetic surgery tax (section 9017 on page 2045)

The federal government would impose a 5% sales tax on cosmetic surgery. Late-night comedians will love this.

I can’t think of another case where the Feds would impose a sales tax. Governors and Mayors usually regard sales taxes as “their turf.” I wonder if they’ll fight this.

Update: Best guess is that it does not apply to braces, but would apply to teeth whitening.

Joint Tax estimates this new tax would raise $5.8 B over ten years. That’s a lot of cosmetic surgery.

This tax would violate the President’s pledge not to raise taxes on those with annual income below $250K.

It would apply to surgery performed beginning in 2010, so get your work done before the new year.

Wednesday, 18 November 2009|
Go to Top